Home Artists Posts Import Register

Content

[This is a transcript with references.]

You and I together are more than the sum of the parts. It’s not just that I know some things you don’t know, and you know some things I don’t know, like, how to prevent hair from looking like sauerkraut. No, there’s more to it. Maybe, hopefully, every once in a while, I point one of you into a new direction, and you see something I couldn’t see. Together we are more intelligent than either of us alone.

But collective intelligence has a flipside: collective stupidity. Sometimes we’re more stupid together than we are on our own. But what makes some groups of people intelligent and others stupid? That’s what we’ll talk about today.

Everything around you is made of just a few types of elementary particles. Fundamentally there’s little difference between you and a cheese cracker. Both are made from up and down quarks, with electrons, held together by gluons and photons. If you combine many of those particles, you get increasingly complex systems. First you get atoms, then molecules, and those molecules can combine to living beings which can combine to societies.

Each time you combine many constituents with their interactions you can get completely new behaviour. We call this behaviour “emergent.” The difference between you and a cheese cracker isn’t on the fundamental level, it’s on the emergent level. You talk. A cheese cracker doesn’t. Or if does, maybe cut back on those THC gummies.  

A simple example of emergent behaviour is a wave. If you combine a lot of water molecules, you get waves. But waves don’t exist for single molecules, this makes no sense. Waves only exist on the collective level. This is what it means for something to be “emergent.” It’s a property that doesn’t make sense on the fundamental level.

It’s not only particles that have emergent behaviour, living beings have, too. People can do a la-ola wave, sheep flow like fluids through gates, and starlings do mesmerizing murmurations.
 
And it’s not only motion that living beings coordinate, they also coordinate the exchange of information. Fungi for example coordinate their growth to optimize the transport of nutrients. According to a study that was just published last year, they do this by using directional memory and collision-induced branching. This emergent behaviour can even be exploited to get fungi to produce microscopic devices. For example, slime mould has been coaxed into growing a network that can transport dyes. In another experiment the mould networks were connected to create logical circuits. While these are remarkable examples of collective behaviour, scientists don’t think that fungi are actually collectively intelligent. Though I think that’s exactly what the fungi want us to think.

The animals that are probably best known for their collective intelligence are bees. They use motion, often called the bee dance, to share information about food sources and they build hives together with a sophisticated division of labour to raise their young. We call them “collectively intelligent” not just because they are able to share information, but because they base decisions on that shared information. They learn from each other.

Ants show similar intelligence in colonies. They communicate with each other by pheromones to signal where food can be found, and together they can defeat enemies much larger than themselves.

But ants also show us the problems with collective intelligence. Ants try to follow each other’s trails and if some of them accidentally draw such trail into a circle, they’ll walk in circles until they die. This “death spiral” isn’t collective intelligence, it’s collective stupidity. It’s what happens when a usually beneficial behaviour goes badly wrong. And the same thing can happen for humans.

“Two Heads are Better Than One” the saying goes, and sometimes it’s true. Contestants in the Quiz Show “Who Wants to be a Millionaire” can ask the audience to answer a limited number of questions for them. The audience then collectively votes on what they believe the correct answer to be. It doesn’t always work but statistically the audience gets it right 91 percent of the time.

The wisdom of the crowds wasn’t born with quiz shows, the idea is much older. It dates back to 1907, when Francis Galton went to a livestock exhibition in Plymouth and asked a group of about 800 people to guess the weight of an ox that was on display. He collected the results and calculated the average value of all estimates.

The result was 1207 pounds, almost exactly the right weight of 1198 pounds. He published the results of this cutting-edge research in Nature. Those were the days people.

Broadly speaking, the reason large groups are better than individuals in answering simple questions is that some people in the group are knowledgeable about the topic and the rest make errors that average out. This tells you that asking the audience isn’t going to make you a millionaire if there are very few people who know the answer. But if you ever need to know the weight of an ox, then asking people at a 19th century farmer’s market is a pretty good idea.

There are more modern applications of this idea, too. Average guesses of crowds are valuable information. It’s why companies use crowdsourcing to collect feedback from some customers to make recommendations for others. It’s why they solicit reviews to judge the quality of products and services. It’s why YouTube wants to know how long you watch a video and whether you can be bothered to click “like”. This information is worth real money. Better still, people provide it for free.

Another example of collective intelligence that you’re all familiar with is Wikipedia. Yes, it has its problems, which is why I have given up correcting the entries on quantum mechanics.But it’s good enough to be useful just by collecting information. Indeed, Wikipedia usefully has an entry about the reliability of Wikipedia that collects studies on the subject. Results depend on topic, but by and large they found that Wikipedia tends to be as accurate as other encyclopaedias, though it’s frequently incomplete, often completely omitting relevant information.

A particularly impressive use of collective human intelligence are stock markets. Yes, they have a bad reputation, but that’s because most of us only take note of the stock market when something goes wrong.

Most of the time, however, stock exchange guides investment to our all advantage. It works because the incentives of individual traders are aligned with the optimal distribution of resources, at least in theory.

But this only works so long as we have appropriate regulations that govern trade. Like, if you signed it, you’re bound to it. If you agree to pay 44 billion dollars for a social media platform and put your name on the paper, you can’t just change your mind the next day. You’re also not allowed to trade insider information, monopolies must be broken up, and there’s a load of other regulations on trade because without them the stock market wouldn’t produce results that we want. It’d still collect information from individuals, but the outcome would no longer be what we desire. And that brings us to the problem.

The problem is, groups are only collectively intelligent when the mechanism to collect their information is carefully set up. If you crowd-source information from a group and want errors to average out, then the members of the group must put forward their private information independently of the others. This means you shouldn’t know what other people have said before you put forward your own guess.

This is why they only show you poll results after you’ve voted yourself. And the “Ask the Audience” is set up that way, too. But if that’s not the case, if people know what others have said before making up their own mind, then the information can become systematically biased. This can lead to all kinds of trouble.

The famous Asch experiment from the 1950s illustrates this. In this experiment, participants were assigned to group with confederates of the experimenter and were asked to match the length of lines on cards with a comparison line. The confederates consistently gave obviously incorrect answers. But many participants agreed with them, even though their own perceptions told them that the answers were wrong.

Now, that the participants agreed with the wrong answers doesn’t necessarily mean they believed them. If I was in a room with a group of people who insisted that the longer line is the shorter one, I’d also agree with them. I’d also keep my back to the wall and inch towards the exit.

That’s why, even though the Asch experiment has been reproduced in many different variants, just how to interpret it has remained somewhat controversial. People might have many reasons to agree with others even if they don’t believe them. But while the interpretation for why people act this way has remained unclear, there’s little doubt that they do.

And this is how information cas’cades work. An information cascade happens when individuals ignore the information that they privately hold and instead pass on the information they obtain from others, for whatever reasons. Like all collective behaviours, this one isn’t necessarily bad. In fact, it’s usually beneficial.

You have all seen information cascades on social media. In the early days of the COVID pandemic, information was sparse and we passed on what little we heard about symptoms and prevention. That’s an example for how information cascades can be useful. But misinformation can spread the same way. This is for example how panic buying comes about. No one actually thinks they need 100 rolls of toilet paper. But if everyone else thinks they need it, maybe these people know something I don’t know. Better safe than sorry!

For crowd judgement to become systematically skewed, it isn’t necessary that people completely ignore their information, it’s sufficient already if they’re influenced. And this happens everywhere around us. Multiple studies have found that information cascades happen for software adoption, online reading, product ratings and other every-day instances.

Since I know you don’t come here for the fluff, sociologists distinguish such information cascades from “herd behaviour”. Herd behaviour just means that individuals behave the same way, but not necessarily that in doing so they ignore their own information. In reality, we often see a mix of information cascades and herd behaviour.

A particularly influential example of herd behaviour comes from an experiment by Milgram in the 1960s. Yes, that’s the same Milgram who did the much-discussed prisoner experiments. But this one was a little more innocent. He recruited a few people to stand in a street corner and point at nothing in the sky. Sure enough, other people came to join them to look at nothing. YouTube is basically built on this idea.

If you come across a video that’s been watched by a million people, you’re more likely to watch it than if it had only 10 views. And most of the time that’s probably a good decision. But it also means that social media has a strong rich-get-richer trend where you eventually end up with some people who are popular for being popular. They’re interesting just because others think they’re interesting.

Many financial crashes are due to information cascades and that’s certainly nothing new. In the 18th century, the Scottish businessman John Law founded the Mississippi Company, whose purpose it was to develop the French territory near the Mississippi river. His stocks sold like warm bagels all over Europe and Law was granted a monopoly on trade.

This was already a bad idea, but things got worse when the French government began printing more money so that everyone could buy more Mississippi stocks. Inevitably, eventually investors realized there was no way the supposed wealth was ever to become real, they tried to get their money out of the bank and the bubble collapsed, leaving many people bankrupt, economic growth seriously damaged, and trust in the financial system in shambles.

The dot-com bubble of the late 1990s worked like that too. Everyone and their dog were investing into internet startups even though no one really knew how those were supposed to eventually make money. The value of these stocks became incredibly overinflated. When those startups eventually went live but created little to no revenue, the bubble burst.

A more recent example of an information cascade was the 2008 financial crash. Banks were handing out mortgages to borrowers who couldn’t reasonably be expected to pay them back. The banks then collected the mortgages and other loans into packages called “securities” that were sold to investors. When interest rates went up, it became clear that these mortgages and loans wouldn’t be paid back. The value of the securities dropped rather suddenly and caused a big wave of bankruptcies.

The 2008 financial crisis is particularly tragic in that it was preventable. Many people working in those banks knew that handing out those loans was a really bad idea that would eventually go wrong. But if they hadn’t played along, they’d have lost their job. So the cascade rolled on.

What do we learn from all this? Can we use some of this information to our advantage?

Well, yes, first of all we learn that if you want to make good use of the collected intelligence of a group, you have to try and find a format in which everyone is comfortable coming forward with their information, and you need a way to prevent one person from being biased by another person, to the extent possible. That is, of course, if coming to an intelligent decision is what you want in the first place. If you want the meeting to be over quickly, then I suggest you ask the most aggressive dude for an opinion first and let him shout down anyone who dares disagree.

Of course making good use of collective intelligence is easier said than done, so let me mention two things that I’ve found useful.

First, we have a natural tendency to focus on the issues that come up more often, but those aren’t necessarily the most important ones. This is why managers like to use tables to identify how important and urgent a problem is before spending time on it. I know that academics tend to find those tables somewhat silly, but it’s indeed a way to prevent collective stupidity. The second useful thing to know is that just reminding people that their opinion might be biased can help to reduce the effect.

That’s for small teams whose decision-making you can influence, but what about the large crowds that you find on social media? One thing that I mentioned already in my earlier video about social media is that just stepping back and thinking about what you’re doing is a way to prevent regrets. And I formulate that so carefully because for some people maybe preventing a cascade of false information isn’t what they want in the first place.

But more interestingly, you can beat the crowd by being part of a group. I know this sounds somewhat contradictory but let me explain.

Numerous studies have found that small groups make better decisions than individuals on objective tasks, that is tasks for which there is an answer that is either “right” or “wrong”, such as “which way is baggage retrieval, left or right”? Ask your fam, and you’re less likely to find yourself next to a broken vending machine at the far end of the terminal. It’s easy to see how this is useful on social media. Not sure whether that email is legit or a scam? Ask a few friends.

Another useful thing to know is that the biggest problem for groups in getting things right is having members which are confident but often wrong. That’s because the confident people make up their mind first, and this then cause an information cascade which sways the less confident people. So be careful around confident people. It’s not that they are necessarily wrong, but if they are, they amplify errors.

Another issue is that we tend to overrate the relevance of our own opinion compared to that of others. It’s called “egocentric bias”. A way to beat this issue is to hold back with forming an opinion, but of course that doesn’t work if everyone does it.

In summary. Making intelligent decisions isn’t easy and we’re not naturally good at it. Whether a group of people makes intelligent or dumb decisions depends strongly on how the information is aggregated. Under certain circumstances, errors can amplify each other rather than cancelling out.

As you see, it isn’t easy to be sharper than a cheese cracker.

Files

Collective Stupidity -- How Can We Avoid It?

Go to https://Nautil.us/SABINE and get 15% off your membership! When we come together in groups we can be so much more than the sum of the parts. But sometimes groups are just much more stupid. Collective stupidity is the flipside of collective intelligence, and we see it a lot on social media. Why are groups sometimes collectively stupid and sometimes not? What can we do to be more intelligent in groups? In this video I explain the most important points. 💌 Support us on Donatebox ➜ https://donorbox.org/swtg 👉 Transcript and References on Patreon ➜ https://www.patreon.com/Sabine 📩 Sign up for my weekly science newsletter. It's free! ➜ https://sabinehossenfelder.com/newsletter/ 🔗 Join this channel to get access to perks ➜ https://www.youtube.com/channel/UC1yNl2E66ZzKApQdRuTQ4tw/join 00:00 Intro 00:45 Emergent behaviour 04:12 Collective intelligence 07:58 Collective stupidity 14:49 What can we do? 18:34 Nautilus Special Offer! #science #socialmedia

Comments

Anonymous

Short, concise, and spot on - nicely done Sabine!

Anonymous

Dr. Hossenfelder mentioned well known phenomenon "ants death spiral", which is flipp side of ant's collective behavior pattern; I just want to add that even birds collective behavior pattern can have a on it's own flipp sid too, which was cought on cameras in Mexico. I mean boids algorithm has it's own down side; boids have a potential to collapse into "singularity" and fall out of the sky. But unfortunately this phenomenon went unnoticed.

Anonymous

Two salient details often go unmentioned when discussing the housing market collapse and subsequent financial crisis. First, the role played by credit derivatives, in particular, a product called Pay As You Go (PAYG) CDS. These instruments magnified the collapse by allowing market participants to wager on the cash flows of the underlying subprime mortgages. Hedge funds bought protection, i.e. shorted subprime mortgages, through these products, while banks and insurance companies (notably AIG, not Lehman) were long by selling the protection, i.e. betting that the cash flows will materialize and absent that, the underlying value of the properties would still ensure a par recovery. These instruments were in turn repackaged into synthetic CDOs, which through the imagined magic of diversification received artificially high credit ratings that made them appear impregnable. The second detail, and the one relevant for today, is why were insurance companies and other asset managers so eager to buy subprime debt? Reminder, the Greenspan Fed cut rates aggressively after 9/11 and kept them low for years. Subprime debt offered inflated yields for an apparently safe asset: a house. Of course, when interest rates finally went up, people were reminded that the value of all assets, houses included, vary inversely with rates. Fast forward 15 years and we have yet another banking crisis because impregnable assets are worth less when rates rise, in particular Treasuries and AAA agency paper.

Anonymous

I think much of the human side of this boils Pathos versus Logos. In the context of a crowd, the ability to reason sometimes breaks down as emotion gets in the way. After all, who wants to be seen as the dummy in the group. Along the same lines, greed plays a big part. Who wants to be left behind in the latest financial scam (subprime loans) or stock craze (e.g., dogecoin). So you have celebrates pitching NFTs on late night television, knowing that for the average person it has to be a money losing venture. Regarding dogecoin, I knew things were about to head south when I saw Elon (yeah, that guy) on a late night YouTube broadcast talking up dogecoin and doing his best trying not to seem desperate. It was days or weeks later than the bottom fell out. But Musk can afford to write off a $300 million loss, while the average person looses their savings and realize they will need to work until they are dead.

Anonymous

This presentation is mostly about modern groups of people, communicating through the internet or in companies. That is a very limited sample. Throughout history people have lived in families, villages and tribes and worked in armies. These might have some different dynamics. For example, in a well functioning family, or a tribe, the well being of others may be strongly coupled to one's own well being. And similarly with the suffering of others in the family and tribes. So this creates a resonant emotional state between the people. Similarly, the people in these older groups may have had more material interdependence than most people in internet groups, or even in companies. So information processing may have been different because of materials processing, and "emotional information" processing.

Anonymous

I don't have anything salient to add to the discussion, but sometimes I do feel very much like an ant stuck walking in a circle.

Anonymous

Please go on to examine the higher levels of collective decision-making: not just making a simply defined choice, but working out together and deciding on a path for achieving some goals, and some priorities among goals. Individual minds are organized to do these things; what are the ways in which collective minds are organized to do them, and which ways are better? We usually think a 50%+1 decision rule is best; others argue for supermajorities. Buchanan won the Nobel Prize for his theory that decisions which induce rent-seeking behavior, such as tax codes, are best made rarely and by supermajorities, so not everyone is lobbying for their preferences all the time. The problem in that case is the unintended consequence of interaction between the collective decision, the process for making the collective decision, and individual follow-on decisions that gain advantages depending on what the collective decision is. But I think he overemphasized the perversities of simple majorities and underestimated the perversities of supermajorities, such as the obsession with finding and maintaining consensus, which we find in international organizations where either consensus is usually needed and occasionally a vote is allowed but only with a supermajority. Then there are those who argue that the individual mind is always better organized than collective minds for thinking through such things, so best to have an intelligent dictator, who will also be smart enough to get intelligent advisers. And then there is the question of "when to call the question", and how to do so. And other rules of parliamentary procedure, such as: how to organize the debate among different sides, with what time allotted to each party or individual; how much more difficult should it be made to reopen a question, once it is decided, than it was to raise the question the first time. And whether these rules, which are carefully written into parliamentary procedure, are applied in the instinctive behaviors of the individual human mind. Does the individual mind, for example, cut off internal mental debate based on an intuition of when the opportunity costs of further deliberation and further delay is greater than that of going ahead with the present risk of error; this being its equivalent of calling the question? And how much obstacle does the mind create to revisiting a question, once resolved? And then there are all the other aspects of rational choice theory. On the other side there are arguments from existentialists and irrationalists like Dostoevsky and Schmitt that open free critical discussion can never reach a conclusion and choices can never be rational, they can only be made on a basis of authority and faith and will, Will, the Act of Decision. Ugh, I think they're wrong but some of their arguments are clever, such as, that we intellectuals put too much pride in our deliberative process since it’s our way of life, so we tend to delay decisions too long and to enjoy too much our game of calling things into question and debating them further. And once we get started questioning authority, there’s no stopping point. I think there’s a lot worth more exploring here, which I think will give further insights into the wisdoms and stupidities of crowds. Thanks for this great beginning on the subject!

Anonymous

https://www.researchgate.net/publication/291222595_The_Infantilization_of_the_Postmodern_Adult_and_the_Figure_of_Kidult Postmodern Openings 40 Introduction Contemporary societies are experiencing a new phenomenon, for which children and teenagers represent the epicenter of the consumerist culture, influencing the media system and forming wishes and behaviors of a growing number of adults: those who Postman (1994) defines adult- children, Epstein (2003) individuals locked in a high school of the mind, Tierney (2004) adultescents, Cross (2008) boy-men. The concept is useful to describe an increasingly recurrent reality: husbands in their forties who spend hours playing the same video games that obsess adolescents, fathers verbally and physically involved in fist fights at their children's game, politicians and managers who behave like impulsive teenagers, young adults who live with their parents, watch cartoons and see in marriage and in parenting an obstacle to their independence. In general, one finds infantile adults, unable to take responsibilities

Anonymous

It doesn't seem possible to make intelligent decisions on the stock market, unlike asking "is the baggage claim left or right", because the answer depends on where others think it is. One might guess the market is bound to collapse, but might pull out too early and miss out on massive gains... Therefore not winning compared to others who waited a bit longer before selling. Anticipating the anticipation is a high-potential but potzntially toxic game, and I can understand why speculation was frowned on or banned for most of the past millennia. With the advent of high frequency trading, beating the market is looking more and more random. We will probably need a worldwide crisis before decisions can be made to ban them.

Anonymous

and then, there are science fashion fads I think we will discover that "Dark Matter" and "Dark Energy" are two such

Anonymous

Humans like to form groups based on criteria that is intended to distinguish real members from fakers. That's why languages are so tricky. A popular criteria is a shared belief. "Let's agree to believe X" is ostensibly insane, but it is definitely in our genes. To be a useful criteria it needs to be something that people outside the group are unlikely to find believable, and hence falsehood is a feature not a bug!

Anonymous

Being an entitled, rude dickhead, being lazy and liking the same stuff one did as a child/adolescent aren't always correlated. These days there's much more media of different sorts to remember fondly than there ever was and we're not all giving up stuff we enjoyed because we're no longer the target audience. This is the perspective I've gathered from social media as a tail-end Gen-X/Elder Millennial from my age-peers and younger adults.

Anonymous

We've had a couple or several of those already, or at least international crises. I'm not hopeful of high-frequency trading getting banned but maybe it'll be more tightly regulated.

Anonymous

Very good discussion. What you discuss is what refutes libertarianism, markets do not control their bad behavior nor avoid catastrophe; Markets require regulation to control them to avoid catastrophic unintended. History is rife with examples of collective stupidity that when unregulated resulted in financial and environmental crises, war, pandemic, etc. For example, the subprime mortgage crisis was the direct result of deregulation, Gramm-Leach-Bliley, that eliminated the Glass-Steagall Act that greatly reduced bank failures and financial bubbles. Also, US federal laws regulating polluting industries improved environmental quality and the Endangered Species Act helped species recover. Not regulating ensures catastrophic results.

Anonymous

I recall reading that Barney Frank, after getting on the board of a big bank, lobbied to overturn Dodd-Frank, which, of course, was a lousy replacement for Glass-Steagall, but was better than nothing. It's rather frustrating that both political parties in the US are under the control of corporate greed.